Misunderstanding gold demand

Most gold market research is based on the premise that the supply side of the market can be characterized by the quantity supplied and demand side by the quantity demanded.  The specific cause and effect relationship between these two variables and price is often unstated; and perhaps rightfully so: is it not obvious that a greater quantity demanded is the cause of a higher price, and that a greater quantity supplied is responsible for a lower price?

No.

This article will show that market forecasts based on quantities of gold are meaningless.  Widespread statements like “Gold demand was up by 15% in 2012” are true but only if they are understood in a misleading sense.  The supply and demand sides of the market consist of supply and demand schedules, not quantities.  A price forecast based on quantities is a non sequitur because there is no causal connection from the quantities to the price.  This error has side-tracked the majority of analysts into an obsessive focus on quantities while ignoring the actual drivers of the price.

The first part of this article will examine the definitions of supply and demand and discuss their relationship to price.  Most analysts define supply and demand as quantities.  There are several ways to do this.  If used consistently, any of these definitions are valid but none of them are useful for the purpose of price estimation.

After establishing the definitions, I will show that the quantities supplied and demanded must conform to an arithmetic relationship that is logically true but has no causal connection with the gold price.  Supply and demand totals can be any numbers that satisfy the arithmetic relationship, while at the same time the price can rise, fall, or stay flat.

The next section will explain the true drivers of the gold price: the supply and demand schedules.  These schedules are not scalar quantities and cannot be measured; they can only be observed indirectly through the gold price itself.  I will show that the cause and effect relationship between quantity and price runs in the opposite direction from what is widely assumed.  The quantities are driven by a temporary disequilibrium between the market price and the supply and demand schedules of investors.  This disequilibrium induces market participants to supply, and to demand gold to bring their portfolio in line with their preferences.

An appendix delves into materials from the CPM Group, a prominent and respected gold market research consultancy, showing how their research relies on the same error.

This article does not entirely stand alone; it builds upon other articles that I have written about the gold market, and on the marginal price theory of the Austrian School.  Some parts of this article will not make sense unless you are familiar with some of these concepts.  I chose to do this partly to avoid repeating ideas that I have already published, and partly to control the length.  I have linked to background material that I believe is relevant.

The Usual Explanation

First, let’s look at the examples. Most published analysis of the gold market is concerned with supply and demand numbers.

From the Telegraph, under the headline, Gold demand increases 15pc:

As the gold price increases, demand for gold and other precious metals has continued to grow. Demand for gold has continued to grow in 2012 and is predicted to increase further next year.  Research by Source, a provider of exchange traded products, shows that inflows into European gold ETPs have reached $6.8bn this year to date, constituting a staggering 15.4pc growth

Almost every page of the World Gold Council’s Third Quarter 2012 Gold Demand Trends deals with either the quantity supplied or demanded by a sector of the market.  The following sentences are selected at random for illustrative purposes:

Third quarter gold demand was up 10% on the previous quarter but 11% lower than record year-earlier levels (p1)

Investment demand was 16% below the exceptional levels witnessed in Q3 2011. (p2)

Total demand (including OTC investment and stock flows) was 2% weaker year-on-year … (p2)

The most significant contribution to the fall in gold demand came from a drop in bar and coin investment.

The World Gold Council’s web site contains the following:

Since 2003, investment has represented the strongest source of growth in demand. The last five years to the end of 2011 saw an increase in value terms of around 534%. In 2011 alone, investment attracted net inflows of approximately US$82.9bn.

My third example cites CPM Group’s 2012 Gold Yearbook Press Release:

Investment demand, the key driver for gold prices, remained at historically high levels last year. Net additions to private investor gold holdings declined to 34.3 million ounces in 2011, down 5.8% from 2010 levels. Even though net additions to private investor holdings slipped lower in 2011, a year in which prices touched a record high, the decline had followed two years of double-digit growth from already high levels of net additions to investor holdings. (p2)

Gold fabrication demand rose 0.6% to 72.9 million ounces in 2011, slower than the 2.3% growth in 2010 due to higher gold prices. Despite higher prices, many consumers sought to purchase more gold jewelry, specifically in developing countries, as a hedge against inflation and form of savings. Developing countries’ demand for gold in the form of jewelry rose to 50.2 million ounces, up from 49.6 million ounces. (p3)

The bearish financial planner Arthur Stein also believes that gold demand is declining (based on the World Gold Council’s figures) which will result in a lower price:

Demand for Gold Declines, Will Prices Follow?

…Demand for gold has been declining worldwide, but prices haven’t. What does this mean for someone investing in gold?

Gold demand declined 11 percent in the third quarter of 2012 compared to the third quarter of 2011, according to the World Gold Council (www.gold.org). Demand fell in every sector except for purchases by central banks.

Market Sectors and Flows

Most gold analysts divide the market into sectors.  This section will discuss how this is done and what the quantities mean in relation to the sectors.  A typical sector breakdown is: mines, industry, jewelry, investors, and the official sector (central banks).  Some writers break the investment sector down into bars, coins, and ETFs.  The choice of sectors is not critical to the points that follow; none of the conclusions would change if, instead of these sectors, flows between countries were used instead.  Some reports combine the two approaches, dividing the developed world market into sectors and treating the rest of the world on a country or regional basis.  Any of these breakdowns would serve equally well.

Below is a list of the sectors, their buying, and their selling:

Sector

Buying

Selling

Mine

Not a buyer

All production sold to the market, where it is eventually refined into investment, jewelry, or industrial products.

Industry

For electronics, dentistry, and other applications that use up gold.

Recovery from scrap

Jewelry

Raw material for fabrication.

Melt from scrap jewelry sold by people who no longer want it.

Investor

Additions to portfolio holdings.

Reductions from portfolio holdings.

Central banks

Add to gold reserves

Subtract from gold reserves

 

Inter-sector Flows and Quantity Balance

The quantity balance between sectors is at the core of most market analysis.  The quantity balance is an equation relating all of the flows in the market to each other.  (A flow is the quantity bought and sold, while a stock is a quantity held by someone over time).  Quantity balance is the requirement that every movement of gold must be accounted for on the buy side and the sell side.  It is similar to the way that double-entry bookkeeping works.  This section will derive the quantity balance equation.  The following section will discuss its significance.

Over a one-year period, every trade that takes place between a buyer and a seller is counted in the following way: the quantity of gold bought (and sold) is added to the buying sector’s gross quantity bought and to the selling sector’s gross quantity sold.

At the end of the year, net flows for each sector are calculated.  The definition of the net flow for a single sector is:

sector net flow = sector total buying sector total selling

Sector net flow can be a positive number, meaning that the members of the sector bought more than it sold; or a negative number, indicating that the members of that sector sold, in aggregate, a greater quantity of gold than they bought.

Assuming that mines sell all of their production, which is nearly always true, mine sector net flow is always a negative number.

mine net flow = mine buying mine selling = 0 – mine selling = – quantity mined

For every trade, the quantity bought is equal to the quantity sold.  This means that the sum of all sector net flows is zero.  By the rules of algebra, this arithmetic identity can be rearranged in several ways:

(1)  quantity mined + net industry + net jewelry + net investor + net official = 0

(2)  net industry + net jewelry + net investor + net official = quantity mined

The CPM Group uses a different sector breakdown than I have used here, so their quantity balance is a little bit different.  They use the following market sectors: total supply (mine plus scrap), fabrication demand (industry plus jewelry), official sector and investment.  Their quantity balance in their partitioning is summarized in equation (3), below.

 (3) quantity mined + industry sold + jewelry sold
= industry bought + jewelry bought + net official + net investor

In this breakdown, official and investor sectors have a net flow on the right side of the equation but the jewelry and industry sectors have gross purchases on the left of the equation and gross sales on the right.

The preceding equations are all saying the same thing: all the gold that comes out of mines ends up as net inflow into one or more market sectors.  These identities all follow directly from the laws of arithmetic.  They contain no new information.  They are only a restatement of the original assumptions, namely, that miners sell all of their production, and that no gold is destroyed during a trade.  The mine sector net flow is always negative but the other sector net flows could be positive, negative or zero.

Gold can be destroyed not in the physical sense, but in the economic sense.  This means that the industrial process renders some of the metal into a form where it would be too costly to recover.  The boundary where recovering gold from industrial use is cost effective depends on many factors, especially the price of gold, which can change over time.  Gold destruction occurs only in the industry market sector.  The rate of gold production always exceeds gold destruction.  Consequently the total of gold held above ground grows over time.

The False Logic of Quantities

I believe that the error of attributing gold price moves to quantities is based on the following invalid thought process on the demand side (with similar thoughts on the supply side not shown here):

  1. The gold price is driven by supply and demand
  2. Supply and demand are quantities
  3. Looking at the demand side, more demand implies a higher price, less demand a lower price.
  4. More supply means a lower price, less supply a higher price.
  5. The key to forecasting the gold price is therefore measurement of gold supply and demand.

Arthur Stein is representative of this type of reasoning.  Quoting at length from his bearish forecast,

Gold is unlike other commodities in many respects. For investors, one of the significant differences is that the supply of gold (called “above-ground gold”) never decreases; it only increases. So declining demand should cause a decline in the price of gold, not an increase.

The sources of total demand are another concern. Jewelry demand has been declining since at least 1997. Jewelry demand in 2011 was 40 percent lower than 1997 and demand in the first three quarters of 2012 was 9 percent lower than the same period in 2011. …  Industrial and dental demand declined in 2011 and is on track to decline another 6 percent this year. …  Investment demand (bars, coins, Exchange Traded Funds, etc.) declined 3% in the first three quarters of 2012 compared to 2011.

The bright spot for gold demand was official sector (central bank) purchases. Central bank activity went from net sales to net purchase in 2010, and net purchases continued to be positive in 2011 and the first three quarters of 2012.

The main problem with this view, as I will show in the next section, is that there is no cause and effect relationship between the quantities and price.

Flows not the Cause of Price

The financial media commonly reports that buying is the cause of the price going up.  Stories in the financial media usually report only one side or the other side of the market.  For example, an increasing number of small investors buying coins is often cited as the cause of gold price strength.  However, the same story could equally well have been written as a bearish report about the increasing number of investors willing to sell their coins.  Either story would be true, at least from a quantitative standpoint and both would be wrong in attributing the movement in the gold price to one side of the market only.

If the reporter accurately described a large volume of coin buying and an equal volume of coin selling, then what conclusion about the price should the reporter draw?  Exactly none.  Buying as such is not the cause of the higher gold price, nor is selling the cause of price declines.  If buying could take place without selling or selling without buying, then one or the other could be an independent cause of price moves.  But neither can occur without the other.  Buying and selling occur always in equal quantities, and, at the same time.  For every purchase of gold by a buyer, an equal quantity is sold by the seller.  The quantity of buying, which is always the same as the quantity of selling, is not the cause of the gold price.

While everyone agrees that the gold price is driven by supply and demand, not everyone who voices agreement means the same thing.  The correct version is: the gold price is driven by supply schedules and demand schedules.  Most analysis of the gold market is based on an incorrect interpretation of the statement, namely, the gold price is driven by the quantity supplied and the quantity demanded.  An increase in gold demand is the cause of a higher price if an increase in demand, means a change in the preference rankings of coin buyers for more gold/less cash.  In that case, all other things equal, transactions would occur at a higher price.

The quantity balance equations are logically valid at all times, but they are accounting identities, not statements of cause and effect [1].  The quantity bought and sold is not an explanation of why the price moved.  All inter-sector flows must balance, but flow is not the cause of the price; it is a summary quantity of gold traded, at whatever price.  Any combination of positive, negative, or net inflows or outflows into any one or more sectors could occur during a year where the gold price was higher, lower, or unchanged.

Suppose during the last year that net investor inflow is a positive number and net official inflow is negative.  This indicates that over one year, investors purchased gold from central banks.  But this fact is an arithmetic identity, not a cause of the gold price movements during this year.  If, the following year, central banks on net purchased gold from investors, we are still no closer to knowing at what price the gold was purchased, and whether that price is higher or lower than the current price.

The True Cause of the Gold Price: Marginal Preferences

The theory of equilibrium price formation is necessary to understand the remainder of this article.  I will not attempt a detailed explanation of the theory here, but the interested reader may find it in one of the following references:  Rothbard shows in detail how supply and demand schedules are derived from individual preference rankings in Man Economy and State, starting with his discussion in Chapter 2 sections 4-5, and Chapter 2, section 8: Stock and the Total Demand to Hold, and then later as applied to money in Chapter 11 (Money and its Purchasing Power) sections 2-5.

Each investor strives to maintain their desired holdings of all potential assets, including cash (i.e. one or more national currencies such as the US dollar or euro).  As their preferences change, and as market prices change, investors adjust their portfolio holdings, at the margin, to bring them in line with their preferences.  The price of an asset emerges as investors balance, bid for assets they wish to hold more of and offer assets they prefer to hold less of.

Supply and demand as they contribute to the price must be understood not as quantities but as schedules.  Market prices balance the aggregated supply and demand schedules of the entire market.  These aggregated schedules are also known as the more widely used supply and demand curves.  In the standard micro-economic presentation, the supply and demand curves intersect at a point, marking the price and the quantity.

I have written about the application of supply and demand schedules to the gold market in Does Gold Mining Matter?  There I explain that the supply schedule for gold (in dollar terms) is dominated by the owners of the world’s existing stockpile of gold, and that mined gold during any one year period has a relatively small impact on the supply schedule.  The price is set primarily by the reservation demand schedules of the owners of the existing gold.  In the same piece, I show that the quantity mined, which many analysts incorrectly believe is “the supply”, has little influence on the gold price.

The quantity balance constraint cannot be a cause of the gold price because balance equations contain only quantities.  The gold price is the quantity of money exchanged for the quantity of gold.  Any explanation of the gold price must contain some reference to the quantity of money involved.  Equilibrium price theory provides a complete theory of the cause of the gold price, taking into account the gold and money sides of the market.

If the gold price is higher now than it was at some point in the past, that can only be due to a shift in preference schedules.  One of the following must be true: 1) either buyers valued the gold more highly and thus were willing to pay higher price, or 2) sellers valued their gold more highly and were only willing to part with it at a higher price.  Historical net flows provide a summary of where in the market were the buyers who valued gold the most highly, and the sellers who valued it the least.

Up to this point I have argued that the quantities supplied and demanded are not the cause of the gold price.  The true causal relationship between price and quantity is nearly in the opposite direction.  Transactions occur in the market because there are some investors whose mix of cash and gold holdings is not consistent with their preferences.  Trading will occur until everyone has adjusted their portfolios, at the margin, to their preferred holdings.  If no one changed their preferences after this moment, and no new gold were mined, then no more trading would occur.

Trading continues because people are always changing their minds about what they want to own.  Individuals who did not previously consider themselves gold investors enter the market; others no longer consider gold a good investment sell out.  The more individual investors that have changed their preference rankings since the last market price, the greater the disequilibrium in the market, and the more change in the ownership of gold and cash is necessary in order for investors to reach their desired holdings.  The volume of trading reflects the extent that holdings of some individuals no longer reflect their preferences.

Attributing a higher gold price to an increase in coin buying alone ignores the equal quantity of coin selling that is necessary for more coin buying to occur.  More coin buying means more coin selling.  The media story about coin buyers driving the gold price higher could be correct, if the buyers are the only ones whose preferences have changed.  In that case they are willing to pay up, higher into the supply side of the market.  But action in the coin shops could also result from sellers liquidating at lower prices, or a simultaneous set of changes by some buyers and some sellers that cancelled each other out in price action, leaving the price unchanged after a large volume of trading.

Demand Schedules Not Measurable

So far I have argued that the gold price is an outcome of the preference schedules of investors.  A preference schedule is not a number.  It is a spiky curve representing a range of quantities and prices.  Schedules are not directly measurable in the way that quantities are, because they include hypothetical quantities that would be supplied and demanded at prices above and below the market.  In order to have the complete supply and demand schedules, the analyst would have to know how much gold would be sold and purchased at every price.  When gold trades, we know only the quantity supplied and demanded at one price.

Laura Davidson explains this point in her excellent piece The Causes of Price Inflation and Deflation.  In reading the quoted passage, it may help to understand that reservation demand for money is another term that means the same thing as the term that I have been using, cash holding preference, except measured against all goods in general.

When the social reservation demand for money changes, it can neither be measured nor observed directly. Whether market participants hoard money, or dishoard it, the amount of money in their wallets and their bank balances in the aggregate remains exactly the same ceteris paribus. There is no special place from which money flows, or to which it flows, when the demand for cash balances changes.

The same point can be made for any good that is demanded in order to be held in stockpiles.  Examples include not only gold but most financial assets such as stocks and bonds.  Reservation demand can be inferred, indirectly, by observing the price.  Davidson continues,

Nevertheless, it is possible to observe the effects of the change [in reservation demand]. Suppose, for example, prices-in-general are falling, and yet the supply of goods in the market has not changed. From this it can be deduced that the exchange demand for goods must have fallen. But let us also suppose the money stock has not changed. This leaves only the reservation demand for money as the causative factor for the reduction in the demand for goods and the ultimate cause of the price deflation.

While I have spent most of this article discussing demand, the supply side of the market works the same way.  Supply schedules and demand schedules together drive the gold price. Supply schedules are immeasurable as are demand schedules.

Conclusion

The main point that I have tried to show is that the demand numbers used in most gold market reports do not measure the demand side of the price formation process.  The same could be said about the supply number.  These two numbers are connected through the quantity balance constraint but they are not the cause of the gold price.

Gold market analysts have a tougher job than other financial analysts.  In Value Investors Hate Gold, I argue that it is more difficult to analyze the yellow metal than equities because quantitative measures such as yield, cash flows, balance sheet leverage, and growth rates provide a fundamental basis for analysis. Gold has none of those things.

The fundamentals of gold are the current purchasing power of money; expectations about the future purchasing power of money; the growth rates of various national money supplies; the volume of bad debts in the system; expected growth rates of bad debts; the attractiveness of other available investments; and the investor’s preference for consumption rather than investment.   These factors do not act directly on the gold price.  Instead, they are focused through the prism of investor preferences, which are not measurable.  The price is the ultimate measurement of how investors view these factors.   Gold presents a paradox: that which drives the price cannot be measured, that which can be measured does not drive the price.


[1] For another illustration of the confusion of accounting identities with causal relationships see Robert Murphy, Krugman Falls Into the Keynesian Accounting Trap.

Robert wishes to thank Mr. James Hickling of GoldMoney.com for assistance in copy editing the final draft.

Tags from the story
Written By
More from Robert Blumen
The deflationary spiral bogey
What is deflation? According to dictionary.com, it is “a fall in the general...
Read More
8 replies on “Misunderstanding gold demand”
  1. says: Gary

    the price of gold ,with almost all gold ever mined still around, and almost no industrial demand, and relatively no new supply, is all about monetary demand.

    gold is money.

  2. says: Paul Marks

    Gary – agreed.

    The media (prompted by Mr Soros and the rest) is fond of talking about the “gold bubble” – in fact the real bubble is the stock market.

    Thanks to Helecopter Ben and his endless pumping of funny money the Dow is now about 14000 (and the British stock market is also high – thanks to the monetary expansion of the Bank of England).

    The elite know the stock market is a bubble – because they have deliberatly created the bubble. Yet they have no shame – and encourage people to throw their life savings down the drain.

    “Interest rates are very low [because we MADE then very low] so you must invest in the stock market”.

    They are even telling them to “invest” in real estate again – the establishnment elite are shameless, utterly shameless.

    The brutal fact is that there is nothing any of us can do for the vast numbers of people who are being cheated.

    The whole thing will collapse soon – and that will be that.

  3. Usually changes in quantity demanded/supplied are contingent on price changes. Changes that occur independently of price are usually referred to as shifts of the entire demand/supply curve(s). So yes, anybody who claims that changes in quantity demanded/supplied causes changes in prices is wrong.

  4. says: Dick Seegers

    I think the stock-to-flow ratio is a good indicator, when it comes to this supply/demand influence on prices in the case of gold. The higher the ratio the less prices are influenced by supply/demand.

  5. says: Mark Cregan

    Supply, demand and price are 3 items discussed extensively in your article. However, you limit your discussion to the real metal and ignore the paper metal (which is 100 plus times as large). This comes from Jeffery Christian in testimony before the CFTC several years back. Basically paper contracts can be issued in whatever quantity is desired to supply the market and thus move the price. This is not supposed to be legal under US commodity law, but happens never the less. Hypothecation, re-hypthocation, re-re-hypohecation, … appears to be legal (not moral or just but legal) under English law.

    Then there are the cases where banks and brokerages have supposedly stored actual metal for customers in allocated accounts, charged storage fees, but never actually bothered to purchase the metal. Major court suits are underway in Switzerland now over this issue. Repatriation of Germany’s gold (the laughably long time to get a small percentage) is another example.

    So the supply/demand cannot be limited to just real metal. More accurately it should read supply 100 paper plus 1 real equals demand of 100 paper plus 1 real. Since a significant portion of the 100 paper consists of people who thought they had real gold (and could get it when they wanted), the price will adjust when they find the thing they know for sure just isn’t so.

    At some point a fraud like this like this will result in a price for a real good, but you can’t actually get the good at that price. This is known as a broken market. A new market will then form whose slogan might once again be:
    He who sells what isn’t his’en buys it back or goes to prison.

  6. says: Peter Reck

    When Central Banks lease out tons of gold, fail to deliver on demand, yet account for the same as holdings on their books, how can any simple supply/demand model function to reflect price? The free market phenomenons we can currently observe in the firearms market shows prices driving supply in many cases. The more “rare” firearms that many had bought cheap and stored (horded) years ago, have one again become available for purchase as prices and demand schedules increase. Throw in the moral hazard and politics (tyranny) of the state and human nature and a somewhat volatile free market takes over. Just like a gun ban, if the state openly considered restrictions or regulations on PM (including any capital controls on physical silver and gold), I believe the demand and supply would explode.

  7. says: Fred

    Excellent paper, my personal take-a-way, if I’m understanding correctly that is: gold as a commodity stands alone from its market pears in that it is cash, as well as a consumable. For this reason the “normal” forces cannot apply. So, for example, the amount of oil coming out of the ground is irrevocably consumed almost immediately, where as the gold mined centuries ago is still being actively traded and re-traded, consumed and then recovered again. Rightly so that Mr. Blumen has focused on the actual physical market as the ETF/paper market is no different than fiat currency, and perhaps even more risky.

Comments are closed.