The adverse effects of monetary stimulation

A number of people have asked me to expand on how the rapid expansion of money supply leads to an effect the opposite of that intended: a fall in economic activity. This effect starts early in the recovery phase of the credit cycle, and is particularly marked today because of the aggressive rate of monetary inflation. This article takes the reader through the events that lead to this inevitable outcome.

There are two indisputable economic facts to bear in mind. The first is that GDP is simply a money-total of economic transactions, and a central bank fosters an increase in GDP by making available more money and therefore bank credit to inflate this number. This is not the same as genuine economic progress, which is what consumers desire and entrepreneurs provide in an unfettered market with reliable money. The second fact is that newly issued money is not absorbed into an economy evenly: it has to be handed to someone first, like a bank or government department, who in turn passes it on to someone else through their dealings and so on, step by step until it is finally dispersed.

As new money enters the economy, it naturally drives up the prices of goods bought with it. This means that someone seeking to buy a similar product without the benefit of new money finds it is more expensive, or put more correctly the purchasing power of his wages and savings has fallen relative to that product. Therefore, the new money benefits those that first obtain it at the expense of everyone else. Obviously, if large amounts of new money are being mobilised by a central bank, as is the case today, the transfer of wealth from those who receive the money later to those who get it early will be correspondingly greater.

Now let’s look at today’s monetary environment in the United States. The wealth-transfer effect is not being adequately recorded, because official inflation statistics do not capture the real increase in consumer prices. The difference between official figures and a truer estimate of US inflation is illustrated by John Williams of Shadowstats.com, who estimates it to be 7% higher than the official rate at roughly 9%, using the government’s computation methodology prior to 1980. Simplistically and assuming no wage inflation, this approximates to the current rate of wealth transfer from the majority of people to those that first receive the new money from the central bank.

The Fed is busy financing most of the Government’s borrowing. The newly-issued money in Government’s hands is distributed widely, and maintains prices of most basic goods and services at a higher level than they would otherwise be. However, in providing this funding, the Fed creates excess reserves on its own balance sheet, and it is this money we are considering.

The reserves on the Fed’s balance sheet are actually deposits, the assets of commercial banks and other domestic and foreign depository institutions that use the Fed as a bank, in the same way the rest of us have bank deposits at a commercial bank. So even though these deposits are on the Fed’s balance sheet, they are the property of individual banks.

These banks are free to draw down on their deposits at the Fed, just as you and I can draw down our deposits. However, because US banks have been risk-averse and under regulatory pressure to improve their own financial position, they have tended to leave money on deposit at the Fed, rather than employ it for financial activities. There are signs this is changing.

Rather than earn a quarter of one per cent, some of this deposit money has been employed in financial speculation in derivative markets, or found its way into the stock market, gone into residential property, and some is now going into consumer loans for credit-worthy borrowers.

In addition to the government’s deficit spending, these channels represent ways in which money is entering the economy. Furthermore, anyone working in the main finance centres is being paid well, so prices in New York and London are driven higher than in other cities and in the country as a whole. They spend their bonuses on flashy cars and country houses, benefiting salesmen and property values in fashionable locations. And with stock prices close to their all-time highs, investors with portfolios everywhere feel financially better off, so they can increase their spending as well.

All the extra spending boosts GDP, and to some extent it has a snowball effect. Banks loosen their purse strings a little more, and spending increases further. But the number of people benefiting is only a small minority of the population. The rest, low-paid workers on fixed incomes, pensioners, people living on modest savings in cash at the bank, and part time employed as well as the unemployed find their cost of living has gone up. They all think prices have risen, and don’t understand that their earnings, pensions and savings have been reduced by monetary inflation: they are the ultimate victims of wealth transfer.

While luxury goods are in strong demand in London and New York, general merchants in the country find trading conditions tough. Higher prices are forcing most people to spend less, or to seek cheaper alternatives. Manufacturers of everyday goods have to find ways to reduce costs, including firing staff. After all if you transfer wealth from ordinary folk they will simply spend less and businesses will suffer.

So we have a paradox: growth in GDP remains positive; indeed artificially strong because of the under-recording of inflation, while in truth the economy is in a slump. The increase in GDP, which reflects the money being spent by the fortunate few before it is absorbed into general circulation, conceals a worse economic situation than before. The effect of an expansion of new money into an economy does not make the majority of people better off; instead it makes them worse off because of the wealth transfer effect. No wonder unemployment remains stubbornly high.

It is the commonest fallacy in economics today that monetary inflation stimulates activity. Instead, it benefits the few at the expense of the majority. The experience of all currency inflations is just that, and the worse the inflation the more the majority of the population is impoverished.

The problem for central banks is that the alternative to maintaining an increasing pace of monetary growth is to risk triggering a widespread debt crisis involving both over-indebted governments and also over-extended businesses and home-owners. This was why the concept of tapering, or putting a brake on the rate of money creation, destabilised worldwide markets and was rapidly abandoned. With undercapitalised banks already squeezed between bad debts and depositor liabilities, there is the potential for a cascade of financial failures. And while many central bankers could profit by reading and understanding this article, the truth is they are not appointed to face up to the reality that monetary inflation is economically destructive, and that escalating currency expansion taken to its logical conclusion means the currency itself will eventually become worthless.

This article was previously published at GoldMoney.com.

Tags from the story
,
More from Alasdair Macleod
The upcoming increase in interest rates
Last week, both Janet Yellen of the Fed and Mark Carney of...
Read More
3 replies on “The adverse effects of monetary stimulation”
  1. says: Paul Marks

    The distorting effects of the increase in the money supply, how it tends benefit some areas of the country at the expense of other and the rich and the expense of the poor, is largely missed by the Chicago School – this is where the Austrian School scores (not treating the economy as a lump – looking at the Capital Structure and the distortion of it).

    More money is NOT more wealth – it is the transfer of wealth from some people (normally poor people) to other people (normally rich people).

    The early 19th century “Barnburner” Democrats of New York State were right about this – as they were about most other things also.

  2. says: joe bongiovanni

    “”There are two indisputable economic facts to bear in mind. The first is that GDP is simply a money-total of economic transactions, and a central bank fosters an increase in GDP by making available more money and therefore bank credit to inflate this number.””
    I’ll give you the first part – but the Fed has not made any more ‘money’ available, as the Fed is not the controller of monetary aggregates, except that which does NOT affect GDP., which is M-0 in the US.
    That bank-credit expands or contracts the GDP is completely out of the hands of the central bank. All it can do is increase reserves, which have nothing to do with whether any bank makes any loan, or not, today.
    It is laughable that the claim is made that it’s the fault of the monetary authority.
    Those poor bankers have no choice but to make any loan on which they can make a profit – THEY are not free to choose the direction of GDP movement, because they are merely sheep following the interest rate herd.
    All laughable.
    To be clear, NONE of those reserve balances have “”been employed in financial speculation in derivative markets, or found its way into the stock market, gone into residential property, and some is now going into consumer loans for credit-worthy borrowers””.
    None of it.
    The funds employed in ALL of those activities were all originated by the bankers who control the credit-money system.
    Here is a more salient point:
    “”The second fact is that newly issued money is not absorbed into an economy evenly: it has to be handed to someone first, like a bank or government department, who in turn passes it on to someone else through their dealings and so on, step by step until it is finally dispersed.””

    Totally true concept, except that newly-issued bank-credit money NEVER goes through a government department. Rather it is those same banks who issue the money into circulation at its most concentrated points of highest return on investment and borrower credit-worthiness.
    “”and so on, step by step until it is finally dispersed.”” (If ever).

    The ones who need it the least get it first and cheapest. That’s why the capital-market money system is the major cause of wealth and income disparity – that big ‘inequality’ bogeyman of the day.

    If the bankers were honest, they would admit that the reason their monetary expansion doesn’t reach Main Street is because they pretty much keep it all for themselves and their friends, and money trickling-down to Main Street is not as fast as the money (interest payments) trickling-up to Wall Street.
    One thing for sure, GUB-mint is BAD.
    Thanks.

  3. says: chuck martel

    Some people are praying for more inflation, namely US college students and recent graduates faced with dump trucks full of student loan debt and increasingly unlikely opportunities to pay off that debt in a shrinking job market. When a double espresso costs $10 a $3 tip for the barrista will help pay for her degree in modern dance.

Comments are closed.