Productivity misconceptions

In the media warm-up for Wednesday’s UK budget, we were told of Britain’s poor productivity and Chancellor Osborne subsequently confirmed that his priority is to address it.

Comparative figures for Europe quoted by the BBC were sourced from the OECD and are replicated in the chart below.

Labour productivity chart

It represents GDP per hour worked, using the US dollar on a purchasing power parity basis across different EU nations. And it shows the UK as lagging other European countries badly, which presumably is why the Chancellor feels the need to act.

These statistics are misleading. France is shown as even more productive than Germany, which cannot be true. France’s unemployment is at 12% and private sector employment is only 62% of the OECD’s “economically active population”. This is not a productive economy. Furthermore the public sector is 57% of GDP, compared with 44% for the UK.

Trying to measure average hourly productivity the OECD way is simplistic and based on assumptions. The formula is GDP divided by total hours worked, so we are being asked to take GDP for granted, when it is in fact an incomplete summation of production value. And in GDP there is no distinction between product commanded onto the market by government and goods and services freely demanded by consumers. And we cannot know hours worked because very few businesses today clock employees in and work out beverage, comfort and lunch breaks.

We can construct a better and more relevant productivity indicator, based on the cost of employment, which is not addressed by the OECD approach. Government, which is an economic cost, should be eliminated from all estimates of production by removing the sector from GDP entirely to isolate the part we actually want, the private sector. The private sector’s costs in supporting the state, the taxes that fund unproductive government spending, should also be removed from private sector GDP. And because we produce to consume, this means as proxy for the cost of government subtracting all taxation from private sector GDP, whether it is on production or consumption.

Next, only the employed and self-employed in the private sector should be included in the divisor by eliminating public sector workers and the unemployed. The result of all these changes produces a very different result, shown in the chart below.

Annual production chart

This information is not only more relevant than the OECD’s misleading estimate of productivity, but it is more useful for international businesses interested in the relative costs of employment.

We should take this one step further and consider the position from our statistically averaged employee. The following table shows the estimated net income of an employee whose cost of employment to an employer is equal to the national average production per private sector worker as shown in the revised chart above.

Europe employment

We now have a new perspective on the subject of productivity. In order to match the high productivity rates shown in the OECD’s productivity statistics, a French worker takes home only €834 per month, and the Italian not much more. For them there’s little point in working. However, the Brit’s take-home pay is more than any of the others, including that of the average German employee.

What this exposes is that the principal determinant of productivity is not the relative skill and dedication of workers as suggested by the OECD’s figures, but the cost of employment. An employer after paying employment and income taxes can less easily afford to pay a living wage in France and Italy. It seems bizarre that official indicators of productivity ignore employment costs, which is after all far more relevant to prospective employers.

Let us hope someone draws this to George Osborne’s attention.

Tags from the story
,
More from Alasdair Macleod
Greece’s referendum
This coming Sunday Greece will hold its referendum. The question to be...
Read More
One reply on “Productivity misconceptions”
  1. says: HJ777

    Interesting article.

    I have long wondered about using GDP to estimate productivity. We know, for example that Ireland’s GDP per head is artificially inflated due to large multinationals being registered there and its comparatively small population.

    I also wonder whether productivity per head is relevant without considering the investment necessary to generate that productivity. If Germany (for example) has more capital-intensive industries than the UK, then the capital cost per unit of output may be higher, i.e. the worker may produce goods of greater value but it may also cost more to do so. Therefore the value added by the worker may not be higher.

    On the other side of the equation may be the fact that the UK runs a large trade deficit, so we are effectively borrowing some of the money we award ourselves in pay.

Comments are closed.