MARK SKOUSEN’S CONTRIBUTIONS TO ECONOMICS By Ken Schoolland, Hawaii Pacific University

“If I have been able to see farther than others, it was because I stood on the shoulders of giants.”  — Sir Isaac Newton

 

Adam Smith, Jean-Baptiste Say, Ludwig von Mises, Milton Friedman, and many others have laid the foundation for sound free-market economics. One more deserves acknowledgement.

 

Mark Skousen’s scholarship has been highly innovative and ambitious in dethroning and supplanting three principle forces in modern economics:  (1) the Keynesian macro model of big government; (2) Paul Samuelson’s popular Economics textbook, which promoted the welfare state, progressive taxation, and an anti-saving mentality; and (3) Robert Heilbroner’s Worldly Philosophers, whose favorite economists are Marx, Veblen, and Keynes.  Market-oriented economists have published numerous critiques of Keynesian economics, but the best way to fight a bad idea is by developing a better idea.  I see Skousen’s efforts as successful in accomplishing this and as a positive contribution to economics.

 

Summary

 

Here is a basic summary of his efforts over the past thirty years, followed by a more detailed explanation:

 

  1. Keynes mutiny: The Structure of Production (1990, 2007, 2015) develops a universal four-stage macro model that challenges the Keynesian/monetarist monolith.

 

Better than GDP:  As part of this 4-stage model, he introduces a new national income statistic, known as Gross Output (GO), that establishes the proper balance between consumption (the “use” economy) and production (the “make” economy).  Skousen identifies GO as the “top line” of national income accounting, measuring spending at all stages of production, and GDP as the “bottom line,” measuring final output only.  Skousen’s GO model demonstrates that business investment, not consumer spending, drives the economy, thus confirming Say’s law over Keynes’s law.   In April, 2014, Skousen’s GO achieved a major triumph when the federal government (Bureau of Economic Analysis) began publishing GO on a quarterly basis—the first new macro statistic since GDP was invented in the 1940s.

 

  1. Exit Samuelson: Economic Logic (2016, now in its fifth edition) is an innovative new textbook that integrates Gross Output and other powerful Austrian/supply-side concepts into standard economics textbooks and re-establishes classical economic policy.

 

  1. Move over, Heilbroner: The Making of Modern Economics (2001, 2009, 2016), a bold new history of the great economic thinkers, offers running plot with Adam Smith and his “system of natural liberty” as the heroic figure.   All economists are judged by whether they advanced or reversed the Adam Smith model.  It won the 2009 Choice Award for Outstanding Academic Title.

 

In short, Skousen attempted to supplant Keynes, Samuelson and Heilbroner – a triple crown in economics.  Here are the details.

 

The Structure of Production (1990, 2007, 2015)

 

Skousen’s first important work is The Structure of Production, published in hardback by New York University Press in 1990, and in paperback with new introductions in 2007 and 2015.

 

Structure is a treatise in macroeconomics and a positive alternative to John Maynard Keynes’s General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (1936).   In the early 1980s Skousen addressed the need for an updated macro model of the economy that challenged the Keynesian/monetarist monolith and did a better job of analyzing economic activity and the business cycle. He was attracted to the Austrian idea, originating with Carl Menger and his intellectual descendants, of a supply-side structure of production involving capital- and labor-using stages of production through time.

 

With The Structure of Production, Skousen created a generalized four-stage macro model based on the ingenious stages-of-production model Hayek developed in his small book, Prices and Production (1931), known as Hayekian triangles.  However, if the Austrian macro model would ever challenge and replace the Keynesian neo-classical model, it required a theoretical approach that needed to be updated, one that would fit historical data and modern macroeconomic statistics.  Given that Hayek’s model never went beyond the purely theoretical level, Skousen created a 4-stage model that is compatible with government statistics, such as price indices, inventories, employment, and national input-output data.  The generalized four-stage model of the economy is illustrated below:

Figure 1.  Gross Output (GO) measures spending at all stages of production.  GDP measure final output only.

 

This model fits well into price indices compiled by U. S. Commerce Department’s Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). For example, for the “resources” stage there is the raw commodity price index.  For the production and distribution stages one could use the producer price index (PPI).  And for the retail stage, there is the Consumer Price Index (CPI).

 

Aggregate Supply and Demand Vectors

 

Structure advances the Hayekian stages-of-production model with the introduction of the Aggregate Supply Vector (ADV) and the Aggregate Demand Vector (ADV) as a way of measuring macroeconomic equilibrium, disequilibrium, and the business cycle.  Here Skousen notes that the supply chain of production is a downward-sloping schedule that reflects distance and direction over time (thus a “vector”).  ASV is determined by productivity, the profit margins at each stage of production, and interest rates.  (See Structure, pp. 201-203, and Economic Logic, pp. 583-587.)

 

The payment schedule for goods and services produced at each stage moves in an upward direction, which he calls the Aggregate Demand Vector (ADV).  ADV is influenced by time preference, the “natural” rate of interest based on the decision of individuals to consume or save their income.

 

Macroeconomic equilibrium is achieved where ADS = ADV at each stage of production (similar to what Mises called the evenly-rotating economy).  When the market rate is artificially reduced to below the natural rate of interest, ADS and ADV move in different directions, and thus create a business cycle.

 

The influence of The Structure of Production can be measured in several ways: as the underground bible for supply-side economics; a revival of Say’s law; an Austrian advance over the Keynesian macroeconomic model and the monetarist disequilibrium model of the business cycle; and a new tool for financial analysis.

 

Its most important function is to serve as a theoretical counterpoint to the standard Keynesian Weltanschauung.  What drives the economy?  According to Keynesians and Keynes’s law, “demand creates supply.”  Consumption drives the production process; consumer spending is paramount, since it represents most economic activity (close to 70% of GDP in the US).  On the other hand, according to supply-siders and Say’s law, “supply creates demand.”  Production drives consumption; saving and investment, technology and productivity, are paramount.  Which force is more important?

 

Introducing Gross Output (GO):

The “Top Line” in National Accounting

 

To answer this question, The Structure of Production introduces a new national income statistic, known as Gross Output (GO), which measures spending at all stages of production in the economy.  GO is defined as follows:

 

GO = Intermediate Production + GDP

 

Or in other words,

 

GO  = “Make” economy + “Use” economy

 

The creation of GO is necessary because Gross Domestic Product (GDP), the most common denominator of economic activity, focuses solely on final output, the end product, or what is known as the “use” side of the economy.  It ignores to a large degree the “make” side of the production process, the supply chain or the goods-in-process at the intermediate stages of production.  As a result, GDP over-emphasizes consumption at the expense of saving and business investment.  By adding the supply chain, GO establishes the proper balance between consumption and saving/investment, between the “use” economy and the “make” economy.

 

Thus, Skousen advocated that national income accounting should have a “top line” and a “bottom line” measure of the economy, just as publicly-traded companies release a “top line” (revenues/sales) and a “bottom line” (profits, net income) every quarter.  GO represents the “top line” in national income accounting (measuring spending at all stages of production) and GDP is the “bottom line” (measuring final output or value added, similar to “gross profit” in corporate accounting).

 

Breakthrough:  The Feds Adopt GO!

 

Good news.  On April 25, 2014, the Bureau of Economic Analysis announced that it would introduce a “top line” measure of gross output (GO) on a quarterly basis along with the “bottom line” gross domestic product (GDP).  In the press conference, Steven Landefeld, the BEA director responsible for the development of the new quarterly gross output data, stated that the new GO by Industry data series offers a “unique perspective” and a “powerful new set of tools of analysis.”  The new BEA “top line” measure is almost twice the size of GDP and much more volatile.  For the latest press releases on the quarterly GO data, go to www.mskousen.com.

 

Both the GO “top line” and the GDP “bottom line” are essential to understanding how the economy works.  As Dale Jorgenson, Bill Nordhaus, and Steven Landefeld conclude in their book A New Architecture for the U. S. National Accounts:  “Gross output [GO] is the natural measure of the production sector, while net output [GDP] is appropriate as a measure of welfare. Both are required in a complete system of accounts.”

 

Many free-market economists consider this BEA announcement the greatest triumph in supply-side Austrian macroeconomics since Friedrich Hayek won the Nobel Prize in 1974.   Steve Forbes editorialized, “Gross output, long advocated by Mark Skousen,. Will have a profound and manifestly positive impact on economic policy and politics.”  It is being introduced into the new editions of economics textbooks (Roger LeRoy Miller, McConnell Bruce Flynn, Colander, etc.).

 

Drawing from the quarterly data compiled by the Bureau of Economic Analysis, Skousen’s research shows that GO (adjusted to include all wholesale and retail business spending) is more than twice the size of GDP and three times more volatile than GDP.  Thus, GO serves as a better indicator of business cycle activity. According to Skousen, GO should be the starting point for measuring aggregate spending in the economy.  It complements GDP and can easily be incorporated in standard national income accounting and macroeconomic analysis.

 

Out of the GO data, Skousen has recently created the quarterly B2B Index, measuring business-to-business (B2B) transactions throughout the supply chain.  This new statistic has been useful in debunking the popular Keynesian myth that consumer spending drives the economy.  Granted, consumer spending represents around 70% of GDP in the United States, but GDP accounts for “final output” only, and is therefore not fully representative of total spending in the economy.  Using adjusted GO and his B2B Index, Skousen finds that consumption accounts for only approximately 30% of total economic activity, and that B2B spending (intermediate spending in the supply chain plus final capital investment) represents around 60% of the economy, and thus is almost twice the size of consumer spending.  This conclusion is more consistent with the leading economic indicators published by the Conference Board.   Again, Say’s law is validated.

 

Economic Logic (5th ed., 2016) 

 

Second, Skousen challenged Paul Samuelson and provided an alternative principles textbook to Samuelson’s popular Economics (1948), which forms the Keynesian basis of most modern-day courses in college economics.  Establishment textbooks, borrowing from Samuelson, use the perfect competition model in micro and the Aggregate Supply and Demand (AS-AD) model in macro, both of which are defective.  Using these models, economists and government officials often support anti-trust legislation, debt financing, excessive consumption, and progressive taxation (all Keynesian mainstays).  Skousen wanted to create a principles textbook that removed bad economic theories and replaced them with sound economic principles on a consistent basis.  He also wanted to write a textbook was based on his experience as a businessman and investor.  Too many economics textbooks are written by ivory-tower academics and are, therefore, too theoretical.

 

Economic Logic (first edition originally published in 2000) establishes a logical step-by-step approach to teaching college economics—thus the title. Skousen’s background in business suggested a new pedagogy, beginning the micro chapters with the profit-and-loss income statement, followed by supply and demand.  His approach is distinctly Austrian, using Carl Menger’s “theory of the good,” which focuses on the quantity, quality, and variety of goods and services rather than earning income as the best measure of standard of living.  Economic Logic is the only economics textbook that begins with the P&L statement (a Austrian-style two-stage micro model), followed by supply and demand analysis.  Classroom experience demonstrated that students preferred this innovative approach over the traditional pedagogy of introducing supply and demand first, followed by profit and loss.  It is also a good way to introduce economics students to business, finance, and accounting, which are often minimized in economics courses.

 

The macro chapters incorporate Skousen’s 4-stage model of the economy (the first to appear in an economics textbook), and integrate the “top line” GO with the “bottom line” GDP and standard aggregate statistics, and business-cycle theory.  GO does not replace GDP, it complements it.

 

He also introduced the Aggregate Supply Vector (ASV) and Aggregate Demand Vector (ADV) as a more accurate approach to the business cycle.  By integrating “Austrian” elements, his macro model more accurately reflects the dynamics of the global economy, including supply-side technological changes, asset bubbles and commodity inflation, and the boom-bust business cycle.  It also reestablishes the virtues of balanced budgets, thrift, and limited government that are absent in Samuelson-style textbooks.

 

Economic Logic also has chapters missing in other textbooks:  the origin of money, and the pros and cons of an international gold standard, central banking, and inflation targeting; the Mises/Hayek theory of the business cycle; a full critique of the Keynesian Aggregate Supply and Demand (AS-AD) model; entrepreneurship, financial markets, and government regulation; a review of major schools of economics, including Austrian, Keynesians, Marxist, Chicago, and Public Choice.

 

In sum, Economic Logic squares the Mises circle and does something not previously achieved:  It integrates Austrian concepts into the standard economics textbook and has been adopted by a number of schools, such as Chapman University, the University of Detroit-Mercy and Universidad Francisco Marroquin in Guatemala.

 

The Making of Modern Economics (3rd ed., 2016):

The Totem Pole Approach

 

Third, and especially popular with students in my classes on the History of Economic Thought, is The Making of Modern Economics.  It was originally published in 2001 by M. E. Sharpe, but is now published by Routledge.  This book reveals a new way to study the lives and ideas of the great economic thinkers.  In my estimation, it the most fascinating, entertaining and readable history I have seen and I have encouraged translations abroad.  So far it has been translated into Chinese, Turkish, Hungarian, and Spanish.  It won the 2009 Choice Award for Outstanding Academic Title (Choice is the official publication of the academic library community).

 

It is a bold history told for the first time as a running plot with a singular heroic figure, Adam Smith and his “system of natural liberty,” at the center of the discipline.

 

Almost all histories of thought have previously been written by socialists, Marxists and Keynesians, with Robert Heilbroner’s classic title, The Worldly Philosophers, being a combination of all three.  His three favorite economists are Marx, Veblen, and Keynes. Heilbroner devotes a chapter to Joseph Schumpeter, but only because he is an enfant terrible of the Austrian school.  Sadly the sins of omission are too great to salvage Heilbroner.  He has virtually nothing to say about J. B. Say, Frederic Bastiat, Ludwig von Mises, Milton Friedman, and, like all other histories of thought, he has no running plot or single heroic figure.

 

On a broader scale, Skousen’s history of economics breaks new ground by rejecting the standard political spectrum, what he calls the “pendulum” approach to identifying economists.  In the world of competing ideologies, the standard political spectrum has Adam Smith, advocate of laissez faire, on the extreme right; Karl Marx, the radical socialist on the extreme left; and John Maynard Keynes, supporter of big government, in the middle.  This pendulum approach is unsatisfactory since it equates Adam Smith with the extremism of Karl Marx and represents Keynes as the golden mean.

 

In The Making of Modern Economics (and The Big Three in Economics, a shortened version), Skousen presents a unique alternative by creating a “Totem Pole of Economics,” where economists and their theories are measured  by their impact on economic freedom and growth.  In his ranking, Adam Smith is on top, followed by Keynes, and Marx is “low man” on the Totem Pole of Economics.

Thus, the story of modern economics begins with Adam Smith, the heroic figure, and thereafter economists are ranked to the extent that they advanced or retarded Smith’s “system of natural liberty.”  Skousen showed how Karl Marx, Thorstein Veblen, John Maynard Keynes, and even some disciples such as Robert Malthus and David Ricardo detracted from the Smithian model of democratic capitalism during periods of economic failure and upheaval, while Carl Menger, Alfred Marshall, Irving Fisher, Ludwig von Mises, and Milton Friedman, among others, remodeled and improved upon Smithian economics as the world economy recovered and prospered.

 

Especially novel, I think, is the contribution of chapter 10, in the middle of the book.  It follows the success of the marginalist revolution that advanced the Adam Smith model and established “neo-classical” economics as a formal science.  Heilbroner and other historians highlighted the sociology of Thorstein Veblen, a major American critic of “neo-classical” economics without providing a counterweight.  Skousen’s middle chapter juxtaposes the ingenious work of Max Weber, the German sociologist who offered a spirited defense of “rational” capitalism.  The two sociologists served as a perfect counterbalance.

 

The Making of Modern Economics also breaks new ground by publishing a hundred illustrations, portraits, and photographs, and offering details and little-known anecdotes about the lives and ideas of the economists, including creative chapter titles and musical selections reflecting the spirit of each major thinker.  Skousen makes the lives and ideas of the great economists come alive like no other textbook, and my students find it especially refreshing.

 

In sum, I salute Mark Skousen for advancing the theory and history of economics and encourage students and colleagues to study his textbooks and insights.

 

Economics Books by Mark Skousen

 

 

Economics of a Pure Gold Standard (Foundation for Economic Education, 1988, 1996, 2010).

 

The Structure of Production (New York University Press, 1990, with new introductions published in 2007 and 2015).

 

Economics on Trial (Irwin McGraw Hill, 1991; 2nd edition, 1993). Translated into Japanese.

 

Dissent on Keynes, editor (Praeger Publishing, 1992).

 

Puzzles and Paradoxes in Economics, co-authored with Kenna C. Taylor (Edward Elgar, 1997). Translated into Korean and Chinese.

 

Economic Logic (Capitol Publishers, 2000, 2016).  Translated into Chinese and Turkish.

 

The Making of Modern Economics (2001, 2016).  Now in its 3rd edition published by Routledge; translated into Chinese, Turkish, Mongolian, and Spanish.

 

The Power of Economic Thinking (Foundation for Economic Education, 2002). Translated into Chinese.

 

Vienna and Chicago: A Tale of Two Schools of Free-Market Economics (Capital Press, 2005).  Translated into Chinese.

 

The Big Three in Economics: Adam Smith, Marx, and Keynes (M. E. Sharpe, 2007).  Translated into Chinese and Vietnamese.

 

EconoPower:  How a New Generation of Economists is Transforming the World (Wiley & Sons, 2008).  Translated into Chinese, Korean, Portuguese and Arabic.

 

About Mark Skousen

 

Mark Skousen is a professional economist, investment writer, university professor, and author of over 25 books.  He was recently named one of the top 20 most influential living economists by SuperScholar.  He earned his Ph. D. in monetary economics from George Washington University in 1977.  Currently he is a Presidential Fellow at Chapman University in California.  In 2004-05, he taught economics and finance at Columbia Business School and Columbia University.  He has also taught at Rollins College (Florida) and Mercy College (New York).  Since 1980, Skousen has been editor in chief of Forecasts & Strategies, a popular award-winning investment newsletter (www.markskousen.com).  He is a former analyst for the Central Intelligence Agency (CIA), a columnist to Forbes magazine, chairman of Investment U, and past president of the Foundation for Economic Education (FEE) in New York.  He has written for the Wall Street Journal, Forbes, the Christian Science Monitor, and the Journal of Economic Perspectives.  His bestsellers include The Making of Modern Economics and The Maxims of Wall Street.  In 2006, he compiled and edited The Compleated Autobiography, by Benjamin Franklin (Regnery).  He is also the producer of FreedomFest, “the world’s largest gathering of free minds,” that meets every July in Las Vegas (www.freedomfest.com).   In honor of his work in economics, finance and management, Grantham University renamed its business school, “The Mark Skousen School of Business.”  Based on his work The Structure of Production (NYU Press, 1990), the federal government now publishes Gross Ouput (GO) every quarter, the first macro statistic to be published since GDP was invented in the 1940s.  Website:  www.mskousen.com.

 

About Ken Schoolland

 

Ken Schoolland is economist, university professor, author, and political commentator.  He is currently an Associate Professor of Economics and Political Science at Hawaii Pacific University.  After earning his BA in political science from American University in 1971 and an MS in foreign service at Georgetown University in 1973, he served as an international economist in the U.S. International Trade Commission, the U.S. Department of Commerce, and on assignment to the White House Office of the Special Representative for Trade Negotiations.  He has taught business and economics at Sheldon Jackson College in Alaska and Hakodate University in Japan.  He is a member of the Board of Directors for the International Society for Individual Liberty, and a Sam Walton Fellow for Students in Free Enterprise.  Professor Schoolland is the author of the acclaimed work “The Adventures of Jonathan Gullible,” which has been translated into 44 languages.  See http://www.jonathangullible.com/

 

 

 

Tags from the story
, ,
Written By
More from Mark Skousen
If GDP Lags, Watch the Economy GO
The Bureau of Economic Analysis will release its preliminary first-quarter growth figure...
Read More
0 replies on “MARK SKOUSEN’S CONTRIBUTIONS TO ECONOMICS By Ken Schoolland, Hawaii Pacific University”