Quantitative methods in economics describe but do not explain

By Dr Frank Shostak

Most economists regard the use of mathematical and statistical methods as the key towards understanding the complexities of economics. They are of the view that in order to be scientific, economics should follow in the footsteps of natural sciences.

By means of mathematical and statistical methods, an economist establishes relationships between various variables. For example, personal consumer outlays are related to personal disposable income and interest rates. Most economists presenting this relation as

C=a*Yd – b*i

where C is personal consumer outlays, Yd is personal disposable income, i stands for interest rate, a and b are parameters. For instance, if a is 0.5, b is 0.1, Yd is 1000 and i the interest rate is 2% then C will be 0.5*1000 – 0.1*2 =499.8.

Note that the parameters a and b are obtained by means of statistical method called the regression analysis.

Is mathematical method valid in economics?

By means of another mathematical formulation some economists also establish that the personal consumer outlays can be depicted as:

C=a*Yd + a1*C(-1) + a2*C(-2) +a3*(Money/CPI)

Where C(-1) stands for consumer outlays lagged by one month, C(-2) consumer outlays lagged by 2 months. Money stands for the stock of money and the CPI stands for the consumer price index a, a1, a2 and a3 stand for parameters.

So how we then to decide which mathematical formula should we accept as the valid formulation of the real world?

For many economists the criteria for the selection of the “right” formula is how well it fits the data. The higher the correlation the better. Unfortunately, a mathematical formulation cannot help us to ascertain what the essence that drives consumer outlays.

Regardless of how complex and sophisticated the formulation is, it does not add to our knowledge of what is behind the fluctuations in the data. A mathematical formulation for consumer outlays just describes the observed outlays. It tells us nothing about the causes for these outlays.

According to Mises to arrive at explanation we need to trace the change in the data back to previously established and identified phenomena.[1]

Furthermore, to pursue quantitative analysis implies the possibility of the assignment of numbers, which can be subjected to all of the operations of arithmetic. To accomplish this, it is necessary to define an objective fixed unit. Such an objective unit, however, does not exist in the realm of human valuations.

On this Mises wrote, “There are, in the field of economics, no constant relations, and consequently no measurement is possible[2].” There are no constant standards for measuring the minds, the values, and the ideas of men.

The main characteristic or nature of human beings is that they are rational animals. They use their minds to sustain their lives and well-being. The usage of the mind, however, is not set to follow some kind of automatic procedure, but rather every individual employs his mind in accordance with his own circumstances. This makes it impossible to capture human nature by means of a mathematical formulae, as is done in the natural sciences.

People have the freedom of choice to change their minds and pursue actions that are contrary to what was observed in the past. Because of the unique nature of human beings, analyses in economics can only be qualitative.

In addition, the employment of mathematical functions implies that human actions are set in motion by various factors. For instance, contrary to the mathematical way of thinking, individual outlays on goods are not “caused” by income as such.

In his own context, every individual decides how much of a given income will be used for consumption and how much for savings.

While it is true that people respond to changes in their incomes, the response is not automatic, and it cannot be captured by a mathematical formula.

An increase in an individual’s income does not automatically imply that his consumption expenditure will follow suit. Every individual assesses the increase in income against the goals he wants to achieve. Thus, he might decide that it is more beneficial for him to raise his savings rather than raise his consumption.

The validity of probability theory in economics 

Modern economics in addition to sophisticated mathematics also employs probability distributions. What is probability?  The probability of an event is the proportion of times the event happens out of a large number of trials.

For instance, the probability of obtaining heads when a coin is tossed is 0.5. This does not mean that when a coin is tossed 10 times, five heads are always obtained.  However, if the experiment is repeated a large number of times then it is likely that 50% will be obtained. The greater the number of throws, the nearer the approximation is likely to be.

Alternatively, let us say it was established that in a particular area, the probability of wooden houses catching fire is 0.01. This means that on the basis of experience, on average, 1% of wooden houses will catch fire.

This does not mean that this year or the following year the percentage of houses catching fire will be exactly 1%. The percentage might be 1% or not each year. However, over time, the average of these percentages will be 1%.

This information, in turn, can be converted into the cost of fire damage, thereby establishing the case for insuring against the risk of fire.

Owners of wooden houses might decide to spread the risk by setting up a fund. Every owner of a wooden house will contribute a certain proportion to the total amount of money that is required in order to cover the damages of those owners whose houses are going to be damaged by the fire.

Note that insurance against fire risk can only take place because we know its probability distribution and because there are enough owners of wooden houses to spread the cost of fire damage among them so that the premium is not going to be excessive.

The owners of wooden houses are all members of a particular group or class that is going to be affected in a similar way by a fire.  We know that, on average, 1% of the members of this group is going to be affected by fire. However, we do not know exactly who it will be.

The important thing for insurance is that the members of a group must be identical as far as a particular event is concerned.

In economics, we do not deal with identical cases. Each observation is unique and not a member of any class – it is a class on its own. Consequently, no probability distribution can be established.

The employment of probabilities in economic analyses implies that a random process generated the various pieces of economic data in similarity to tossing a coin.

Note that random means arbitrary i.e. without method or conscious decision. However, if this had been the case human beings would not be able to survive for too long.

In order to maintain their life and wellbeing, human beings must act consciously and purposefully. They must plan their actions and employ suitable means.

Summary and conclusions

Human action cannot be analyzed in the same way that one would analyze objects. Various quantitative methods are a way of describing but not explaining events.

These methods do not improve on our knowledge of the driving causes in economics.

A major problem of using mathematics in economics is that it distracts economists from thinking about the essence of what causes economic events.

To make sense of historical data one must scrutinize it not by means of quantitative methods but by means of trying to grasp and understand how it emerged.


[1] Ludwig von Mises Human Action Contemporary Books, Inc. Chicago p 571.

[2] Human Action, p.55.

Tags from the story
More from Dr Frank Shostak
Why the positive time preference theory valid despite data contradiction?
In the Mises Institute daily articles column the Wire on November 21...
Read More
0 replies on “Quantitative methods in economics describe but do not explain”