The Keynesian multiplier – myth or reality?

By Dr Frank Shostak 

For most economists and financial commentators, the heart of economic growth is the demand for goods and services. It is also held that the economy’s total output as depicted by gross domestic product (GDP) increases by a multiple of the increase in the demand.

Let us say that out of an additional dollar received individuals spend $0.9 and save $0.1. Now, let us also assume that consumers have increased their expenditure by $100 million. As a result of this increase, retailers’ revenue increased by $100 million. Retailers in response to the increase in their income consume 90 percent of the $100 million, i.e., they raise expenditure on goods by $90 million. The recipients of the $90 million spend in turn 90 percent of the $90 million, i.e., $81 million. Then the recipients of the $81 million spend 90 percent of this sum, which is $72.9 million and so on. Note that the key feature here is that the expenditure by one person becomes the income of another person.  

At each stage in the spending chain individuals spend 90 percent of the additional income they receive. This process eventually ends, with the total GDP increases by $1 billion (10*$100 million) i.e. by the multiple of 10.

Note the larger is the multiplier, the more is being spent out of additional income, and therefore the impact of the initial spending on the overall output is larger. For instance, if individuals change their habits and spend 95 percent out of each dollar the multiplier will become 20. If they decide to spend only 80 percent and save 20 percent then the multiplier will be 5. This means that the less is saved the larger the impact on overall output per increase in overall demand. The popularizer of the multiplier, John Maynard Keynes, wrote,

If the Treasury were to fill old bottles with banknotes, bury them at suitable depths in disused coal mines which are then filled up to the surface with town rubbish, and leave it to private enterprise on well-tried principles of laissez-faire to dig the notes up again (the right to do so being obtained, of course by tendering for leases of the note-bearing territory), there need be no more unemployment and with the help of the repercussions, the real income of the community, and its capital wealth also, would probably become a good deal greater than it actually is.

Following this logic, it is not surprising that some economists are of the view that by means of fiscal and monetary stimulus it is possible to prevent an economy falling into a recession. On this, the former Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke had even suggested that there is good evidence that cash that goes to low- and moderate-income individuals is more likely to be spent in the near term – hence from this perspective it is going to be more beneficial for economic growth. 

Is the multiplier model complying with reality?

Is more savings bad for the economic growth, as the multiplier model indicates?  Now if a producer of consumer goods produces an amount that is only adequate for the personal needs of that producer, then there is nothing left for the exchange with the other producers of goods. Note that the excess of output versus the amount allocated for sustenance is savings. 

Now, the owners of consumer goods, rather than exchanging these goods for other consumer goods, could decide to use the saved consumer goods to secure better tools and machinery. With better tools and machinery, a greater output and a better quality of consumer goods can be produced some time in the future. 

Note that by transferring a portion of their consumer goods to the production of tools and machinery the producers of consumer goods are transferring their savings to individuals that specialize in making these tools and machinery. Savings sustain these individuals whilst they are busy making capital goods.

Once capital goods are made this permits an increase in the overall production of consumer goods. As the flow of production expands all other things being equal, this makes it possible for more savings, which in turn enables a further increase in the production of tools and machinery. This in turn makes it possible to further increase the production of consumer goods. So, contrary to the popular thinking, more savings expands, rather than contracts, the production flow of consumer goods.

Hence, the increase in production is dependent on the enhancement and the expansion of the infrastructure i.e. capital goods. The increase in savings in turn permits the expansion and the enhancement of the infrastructure. It follows then that production is not constrained by the consumers’ demand but by savings. Consequently, without the increase in savings no increase in output is going to take place.

Let us examine the effect of an increase in the government’s demand on an economy’s overall output. Note that the government is not a wealth producer. It is dependent on the wealth generators. Can an increase in the government’s demand give rise to more output as popular thinking has it? On the contrary, it will impoverish producers. Producers will be forced to part with their products in an exchange for non-wealth and this in turn will weaken the flow of production of consumer goods. 

Not only does the increase in government outlays do not raise the overall output by a positive multiple, but on the contrary, this leads to the weakening in the process of wealth generation in general. According to Mises,

…there is need to emphasize the truism that a government can spend or invest only what it takes away from its citizens and that its additional spending and investment curtails the citizens’ spending and investment to the full extent of its quantity. 

Furthermore, according to Mises,

An essential point in the social philosophy of interventionism is the existence of an inexhaustible fund, which can be squeezed forever. The whole system of interventionism collapses when this fountain is drained off: The Santa Claus principle liquidates itself.

Money and the Keynesian multiplier 

Paraphrasing Jean Baptiste Say, Mises held that,

Commodities, says Say, are ultimately paid for not by money, but by other commodities. Money is merely the commonly used medium of exchange; it plays only an intermediary role. What the seller wants ultimately to receive in exchange for the commodities sold is other commodities. 

When an individual increases his spending by $100 all it means is that he has lowered his demand for money by $100. This also means that the seller’s demand for money has increased by $100. All this, however, doesn’t give rise to an overall increase in output, as suggested by popular thinking. 

Likewise, if the seller now spends 90 percent of $100 all that we will have here is a situation wherein his demand for money has fallen by $90. Somebody else’s demand for money has risen by $90. 

Within all other things being equal, if individuals have increased their expenditure on some goods, then they will be forced to spend less on some other goods. This means that the overall spending in an economy remains unchanged.

Only if the amount of money in the economy increases, all other things being equal, will spending in money terms follow suit. However, in this case the increase is because of the increase in money supply. 

The increase in the monetary expenditure because of an increase in money supply cannot however generate the expansion in output as the popular thinking has it. All that it will cause is a reshuffling of the existent savings. It will enrich the early receivers of the new money at the expense of the later receivers or no receivers at all. 

Obviously, then, an expansionary monetary policy which is aimed at boosting the economy’s demand cannot increase the overall output by a multiple of the initial increase in the demand. 

Summary and conclusion

John Maynard Keynes’s ideas remain the driving force of economic policy makers at the Fed and government institutions. 

The heart of the Keynesian philosophy is that what drives the economy is the demand for goods and services. Economic recessions are predominantly the result of insufficient demand. In the Keynesian framework an increase in the total demand raises the output by a multiple of the initial increase in the demand. 

In the real world, an artificial boost in the total demand that is not preceded by production leads to the depletion of savings and, contrary to the popular view, to the shrinking in the flow of wealth i.e. it results in the economic impoverishment. 

More from Dr Frank Shostak
Can quantitative easing lift economic growth?
Some commentators such as Mohamed El-Erian, the chief executive officer of Pacific...
Read More
Leave a comment

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *