The only game worth playing

“I cannot leave this subject as though its just treatment wholly depended either on our own pledges or economic facts. The policy of reducing Germany to servitude for a generation, of degrading the lives of millions of human beings, and of depriving a whole nation of happiness should be abhorrent and detestable, – abhorrent and detestable, even if it were possible, even if it enriched ourselves, even if it did not sow the decay of the whole civilized life of Europe. Some preach it in the name of Justice. In the great events of man’s history, in the unwinding of the complex fates of nations Justice is not so simple. And if it were, nations are not authorized, by religion or by natural morals, to visit on the children of their enemies the misdoings of parents of rulers.”

– John Maynard Keynes, ‘The Economic Consequences of the Peace’, cited by George Cooper.

 

Probably the most powerful metaphor in the otherwise dismal history of economics is Frédéric Bastiat’s broken window fallacy. It runs as follows. A shopkeeper’s son happens to break one of his windows. It attracts a crowd. Pretty soon they say to each other, “It’s an ill wind that blows nobody any good. People need to make a living. This will be good news for the glazier.” A glazier duly arrives, and is paid six francs for his repairs. Perhaps we should break more windows. Money will circulate throughout the economy. Glaziers will benefit.

Bastiat then addresses the crowd directly:

“Stop there ! Your theory is confined to that which is seen; it takes no account of thatwhich is not seen.”

The crowd sees and hears the six francs jangling in the glazier’s pocket. They anticipate the economic frenzy that will develop when those six francs are spent. What the crowd does not see is what the shopkeeper might have done with those six francs that he has now handed over to the glazier. His employment of those six francs in some more productive way is not seen, because it can now never happen.

“If that which is not seen is taken into consideration, because it is a negative fact, as well as that which is seen, because it is a positive fact, it will be understood that neither industry in general, nor the sum total of national labour, is affected, whether windows are broken or not.”

Bastiat’s metaphor only gets more powerful over time as the world economy gets more and more financialised, and as more and more capital flows in ways that are somewhat less than fully transparent. But the world’s a big place – it would be foolish to think that we can always ‘see’ what’s going on, let alone take account of what, per Bastiat, we plainly cannot see.

So there will no doubt be plenty of wild theorising flying around as the latest act in the ongoing Greek tragedy plays out in the financial markets. What we do know, though, is that after the bailouts of 2010, Greek debt of questionable value which had been held predominantly by French and German banks of similarly questionable value, through the good offices of the European Commission, the ECB and the IMF, suddenly became the liability of Europe’s taxpayers. None of this was done in any way that can be described as democratic. It was done by unelected bureaucrats. But it was clearly done for political reasons – the euro zone project stopped being about economic matters, if it ever even was, some years back.

Another European whose observations are worthy of note in the midst of this crisis is the Austrian economist Leopold Kohr. Whereas the Scottish moral philosopher Adam Smith wrote about the wealth of nations, Kohr’s magnum opus was entitled ‘The breakdown of nations’. Kohr was born in the tiny village of Oberndorf in central Austria. The size of his birthplace would prove to be a constant influence on Kohr’s world outlook. Kohr believed that there were unavoidable limits to the expansion of societies:

“..social problems have the unfortunate tendency to grow at a geometric ratio with the growth of an organism of which they are a part, while the ability of man to cope with them, if it can be extended at all, grows only at an arithmetic ratio.”

As far as Leopold Kohr was concerned, only small states could constitute true democracies, because only in small states could the citizen have direct influence over the governing authorities. Probably the best example of such devolved and localised democracy in Europe today is Switzerland – which continues, not incidentally, to be one of the most successful economies in the world, despite – in huge opposition to the conventional ‘wisdom’ on the topic – maintaining a strong currency.

“We have ridiculed the many little states,” wrote Kohr, sadly,

“Now we are terrorised by their few successors.”

Professor Albert Bartlett of the University of Colorado was another thinker wary of gigantism.

His 70 minute presentation ‘Arithmetic, Population and Energy’ remains the most impressive presentation on YouTube I have ever seen.

Professor Bartlett’s thesis was that mankind’s biggest failure is our inability to understand the power of the exponential function. The exponential function describes anything that grows by a fixed percentage over time. He uses the example of bacteria growing in a bottle. At 11 o’clock the bottle is empty, bar one bacterium. By 12 o’clock the bottle is full. The doubling time – the time it takes for the bacteria to double in number – is a minute. He then asks: at what time is the bottle half full ?

The answer may surprise you: at just one minute to mid-day.

What applies to bacteria in bottles also applies to the human population on our planet and to the world’s natural resources. To cut to Bartlett’s chase, he asks:

“Can you think of any problem in any area of human endeavour on any scale, from microscopic to global, whose long term solution is in any demonstrable way aided, assisted or advanced by further increases in population locally, nationally or globally ?” As he states, equally starkly,

“Continued growth past maturity for any entity becomes obesity or cancer.”

Contrary to popular belief and widespread political deception, the world has seen no great deleveraging since the financial crisis. As McKinsey recently pointed out, global debt has actually risen since 2007 by some $57 trillion.

And debt is a tricky asset class. While it constitutes an asset to the holder, it is clearly a liability for the issuer, who has every incentive under the sun to devalue it. That conflict of interests is bad enough. It is made worse by the fact that ‘investment’ in debt is conducted almost exclusively by institutional players – fund managers who, at a personal level, have little or no skin in the game, and who conduct their investment operations almost entirely in obedience to the illogic of bond indexation, whereby the largest components of a bond index are the most heavily indebted and therefore least creditworthy issuers of that debt.

Bastiat showed that what we think we see is often dwarfed by the impact of things we cannot see and in some cases cannot even begin to understand. The tectonic plates of the global debt market, we suspect, are starting to shift, in what may become some very uncomfortable ways, that are likely to hugely imperil the capital of bondholders, creditors and others not necessarily directly linked to the bond market at all.

The very role of bonds in 2015 has become hopelessly distorted. This is an asset class historically associated with the generation of income and the preservation of capital. Interest rates are now so derisory and so politicised that the purpose and function of bonds in an investment portfolio no longer has any validity.

To us the conclusion is clear. If you cannot understand the game, then do not play the game. The rational investment answer lies not in overvalued credit markets but in undervalued equity markets, provided they can be found. Notwithstanding the likely market volatility associated with the ongoing Greek black comedy, high quality and‘value’ stocks seem, to our way of thinking, to be the only game in town that is really worth playing any more.

Written By
More from Tim Price
Party on! (or not)
“The sea’s freezing. A man won’t last long in that. We’ve drawn...
Read More
One reply on “The only game worth playing”
  1. Thank you for a very nice essay.

    Something to remember with beautiful quotes.

    And an ending with which I agree – but are there any such investments left?

Comments are closed.